Why 'Free Market' Foreclosures Destroy Communities As Effectively As Any Central Planner

While central planners reshaped communities in their own image, mortgage servicers tear them apart to maximize their profits.

Today is National Day of Action on Foreclosures. Occupy Our Homes has created a list events at their site. Here’s a great video on what is going on in Brooklyn, which shows the devastation happening there:

Between 1853 and 1869, Baron Haussmann tore down and rebuilt major parts of Paris according to principles of hygiene and circulation. He installed roads, sewers, and other public works and demolished neighborhoods, rebuilding them alongside modern technology. These neighborhoods became more stratified by class and function and more easily controlled by state forces.

A general critique of city planners like Haussman is that they rebuilt their cities in order to make it, in James Scott’s phrase, seeable by the state. This reconstruction of Paris was focused on simplification, legibility, and centralized, managerial control, regardless of the local knowledge and practices destroyed in the recreation. Critiques like this extend across modernity, especially to those Americans like Robert Moses who built highways through major metropolitan areas.

Though Scott was looking towards models of embeddedness developed by those like Karl Polyani, most people who develop these critiques invoke Hayek and the price system of the market as the superior way of planning. The profit-motive of the price system coordinates information across a vast network of agents who will never know each other. This allows for the most efficient use of society’s resources. By seeking out profit opportunities, individuals will coordinate the whole.

There have been millions of foreclosures over the past several years and there will be millions more in the next few years. They are reworking neighborhoods in much the same way Baron Haussmann once did — but this time the process is driven by the free market of financial capital rationally seeking profit rather than a central planner dreaming about how to make a city “modern.” How are the results?

The central agents in this story are mortgage servicers. Servicers are entities that accept payments from borrowers. They also handle mortgages that become distressed and are the entities responsible for modifying them. They are distinct from the company that lent out the money. With the vast majority of mortgages now having run through this relatively new servicing model, one created alongside the slicing-and-dicing model that took over consumer finance, this is the key type of entity responding to the profit motive in the mortgage payment market.

How do the mortgage servicers earn their profit? At their core, they respond to three principal-agent problems in their “Pooling and Service Agreement” contracts. As Adam Levitin and Tara Twomey argue convincingly:

[S]ervicers do not have a meaningful stake in the loan‘s performance; their compensation is not keyed to the return to investors. Second, the servicing industry’s combination of two distinct business lines – transaction processing and default management — encourage servicers to underinvest in default management capabilities, leaving them with limited ability to mitigate losses. Servicers’ monetary indifference to the performance of a loan only exacerbates this situation…

Servicers’ incentives in managing individual loans do not track investors’ interests. This creates three interrelated problems. First, servicers are incentivized to pad the costs of handling defaulted loans at the expense of investors and borrowers. Second, servicers are not incentivized to maximize the net present value of a loan, but are instead incentivized to drag out defaults until the point that the cost of advances exceeds the servicer‘s default income. In other words, servicers are incentivized to keep defaulted homeowners in a fee sweat box rather than moving to immediately foreclose on the loan. Third, servicers are incentivized to favor modifications that reduce interest rates rather than reduce principal, even if that raises the likelihood of redefault.

Here’s a chart from the National Consumer Law Center’s report “Why Servicers Foreclose When They Should Modify and Other Puzzles of Servicer Behavior” (pdf) by Diane E. Thompson that outlines the logic of how services handle mortgages in trouble:

To expand for a second on their incentives, they include:

Maximizing fees. As a result of the servicing “Pooling and Service Agreement” contracts, servicers have an incentive to push borrowers into default and keep them there. The fees associated with them go straight to the servicer. And if the loan goes into foreclosure, the servicer is paid first before the investor recoups any money. So fee pyramiding and/or loading a loan up with fees to the point where it becomes difficult for the borrower to pay and then foreclosing without modification — a nightmare scenario for both the borrower and lender — is fantastic for the servicing firm.

Making bad modifications. If debt goes bad, there should be a good-faith effort to successfully work it out and modify it before a foreclosure happens. As Lou Ranieri, the pioneer of the mortgage-backed security puts it, “You are almost always better off restructuring a loan in a crisis with a borrower than going to a foreclosure… If we keep letting these things go into foreclosure it’s a feedback loop where it will ultimately crush the consumer economy.” Since servicers are paid as a percent of principal, they have an incentive to make modifications that increase principal and reduce interest rates, even if these loans aren’t sustainable. This goes double if they have exposure to junior-lien debts.

Quick turnaround without proper legal attention. Since the system is designed for servicing to be a thin business model, there is no infrastructure, nor means by which investors can force one to be created, to handle a troubled housing market. Proper staffing is a sunk cost that isn’t easily recouped. It shouldn’t surprise us that informants are saying that:

20% of files with phantom referrals, approximately another 35% of files had some problems in them. Those problems varied, and included among others, an ARM that had improperly adjusted up, a failure to properly account for a borrower’s principal and interest payments, and a failure to properly attribute payments between pre-petition and post-petition that led the banks to try to collect pre-petition obligations they were not permitted to pursue.

These all add to fee income.

So this is the fruit of the private securitization market that is now running our mortgage markets. What I find fascinating is that the key things that are motivating servicers in their profit-maximizing don’t aggregate widely-dispersed information in the way Hayek described in The Use of Knowledge in Society. They aren’t signaling, or absorbing the signals of, relative prices of scarcity or substitution. They aren’t reacting to an increase in the price of tin without having to care why it has increased, nor are they increasing the price of tin by selling less of it, influencing people they’ll never meet.

As Thompson puts it, “How servicers get paid and for what is determined in large part by an interlocking set of tax, accounting, and contract rules.” At their core, they are reacting to the laws we use to restructure debt in bankruptcy, the prioritization of multiple liens in distressed debt, REMIC tax law, standardized contracts with poor monitoring of agents, a lack of enforcement of foreclosure laws, and, most importantly, the ability to skim off the top. If you look at the chart of incentives for servicers above, none of them are really relevant to either taking in or sending out information about the mortgage market.

We shouldn’t think of any of these things that force homeowners into bankruptcy as reflecting any marginal information about housing, homeowners’ ability and willingness to pay, or the availability of capital. They are a combination of laws we’ve chosen for ourselves about the managing of private property in housing and debt and a standardized contract among a handful of big financial firms that have ended up in a vicious battle over monitoring of the servicers themselves. And that doesn’t even get to the externalized costs of a foreclosure to the community. The model is driven not by an abstract invisible hand but by the very real laws and contracts in which they are embedded. When those laws and contracts are faulty — as they are here — no useful information or allocation happens.

Which is all to say, if we had a central planning team of Baron Haussmann, Robert Moses, Le Corbusier, and Lenin running the United States mortgage market, I can’t imagine they’d do more damage to our neighborhoods and communities than Bank of America’s servicing arm is currently doing.

Mike Konczal is a Fellow at the Roosevelt Institute.

Cross-Posted From The Roosevelt Institute’s New Deal 2.0 Blog

The Roosevelt Institute is a non-profit organization devoted to carrying forward the legacy and values of Franklin and Eleanor Roosevelt.

Start your day with National Memo Newsletter

Know first.

The opinions that matter. Delivered to your inbox every morning

How A Stuttering President Confronts A Right-Wing Bully

Donald Trump mocks Joe Biden’s stutter,” the headlines blare, and I am confronted (again) with (more) proof that the presumptive Republican presidential nominee hates people like me.

Keep reading...Show less
Trump at Trump Tower

Former President Donald Trump at Trump Tower in Manhattan

NEW YORK, March 25 (Reuters) - Donald Trump faces a Monday deadline to post a bond to cover a $454 million civil fraud judgment or face the risk of New York state seizing some of his marquee properties.Trump, seeking to regain the presidency this year, must either pay the money out of his own pocket or post a bond while he appeals Justice Arthur Engoron's February 16 judgment against him for manipulating his net worth and his family real estate company's property values to dupe lenders and insurers.

Keep reading...Show less
{{ post.roar_specific_data.api_data.analytics }}